Ball's Critical Mass

A week or two ago I finally finished reading Philip Ball's Critical Mass : How One Thing Leads to Another. New York : Farrar, Straus and Giroux, 2004. (My book note about it, with different quotations, is here.)

I've become quite a fan now of Philip Ball's writing; previously I was wowed by Bright Earth, and The Ingredients. Happily for me, there are still some of his books that I haven't read.

This one struck me very personally in a couple of ways. Loosely speaking, it's about modern attempts to apply modern concepts in condensed-matter physics (encompassing thermodynamics, statistical physics, fluid dynamics, critical phenomena, chaos theory and others) to social systems and the collective behavior of humans. Once upon a time I did experimental research in condensed-matter physics, including several of the disciplines he talks about. Today, with Ars Hermeneutica, I'm quite interested in what I call "appropriate quantification", or how to apply statistical models to collective human behavior. Thus, there is a lot of resonance here. When I think about how irritating this book could have been had it been written by a less-accomplished science writer, it makes me admire Ball's talents that much more.

These are some excerpts that I marked to keep here in my common-place book.

To kick things off, here's an excerpt he quotes from C.P. Snow's famous book The Two Cultures, about the divide (real or imagined) between the sciences and the humanities. This is all Snow:

A good many times I have been present at gatherings of people who, by the standards of the traditional culture, are thought highly educated and who have with considerable gusto been expressing their incredulity at the illiteracy of scientists. Once or twice I have been provoked and have asked the company how many of them could describe the Second Law of Thermodynamics. The response was cold: it was also negative. Yet I was asking something which is about the scientific equivalent of: Have you read a work of Shakespeare's. [p.38 of Critical Mass]

Ball began his discussion by looking at the earliest attempt to make a science of social interaction, Hobbe's Leviathan. Later on, he wrote about how earlier ideas propagated into today's economic thinking.

The social contract proposed by Hobbes might sound like a forerunner of those advocated by John Locke (1623–1704) and Jean-Jacques Rousseau (1712–1778), but it is instead the reverse. To Locke and Rousseau, the power conferred upon the head of state comes with an obligation to serve the interests of the populace; for Hobbes, the common people are contracted to serve their ruler. For Hobbes, the principal fear was of anarchy; for Locke it was the abuse of power, which is why he saw the need for safeguards to avoid absolutism.

But although apparently a proponent of autocracy, Hobbes also provides arguments that can be used to support both bourgeois capitalism and liberalism. Although he expressed an aversion to the way the mercantile society bred men whose "only glory [is] to grow excessively rich by the wisdom of buying and selling," which they do "by making poor people sell their labour to them at their own prices," he saw bourgeois culture as largely inevitable, and sought a system that would accommodate its selfish tendencies without conflict. To this end he left it to the market to assign the value of everything, people included: "The value of all things contracted for, is measured by the Appetite of the Contractors: and therefore the just value, is that which they be contracted to give." This fee-market philosophy found voice in Adam smith's Wealth of Nations in the following century. Those in Britain and the United States (and indeed elsewhere) who lived through the 1980s will recognize it as an attitude that did not wane with the Age of Enlightenment. [p. 29]

After we'd spent quite a bit of time using scientific models to understand some of the complexity of the market and larger economic systems, suddenly traditional economic theories seems hopelessly naive and more the product of wishful thinking than critical thinking.

So deeply entrenched is the free-market philosophy in American economic theory today (I am talking here about the pundits who exert a real influence–the TV analysts, the Wall Street Journal op-ed columnists, the think-tankists, and all too often the White House advisors–but not the academic economists) that the supporters of this creed are hoping even to ride out the catastrophic stock market collapse that is proceeding at full throttle at the time of writing. They place the blame on a few corrupt CEOs, on government policies, on fickle small investors, on labor unions, on left-wing critics who spread doubt and negative thinking–anywhere but on the market itself. If only all these people would behaved, say the free-marketeers, stocks would keep rising forever. [pp. 224–225]

Later, he moved on to using ideas from critical phenomena to look at systems that can apparently change their states spontaneously and suddenly. The key concept here is that of thermodynamic fluctuations.

One experimental peculiarity that the theory [a late 19th century by physicist van der Waals) did embrace was the extraordinary sensitivity of the critical point. A system near its critical state becomes extremely responsive to disturbances. If you squeeze a substance, it shrinks in volume. The resistance it offers to the is compression is a measure of its so-called compressibility A rubber ball is more compressible than a steel, ball, and a gas is typically much more compressible than a liquid–one can squeeze it more easily. At the critical point of a liquid and gas, the fluid becomes absurdly compressible–in fact, more or less infinitely so. In principle, the gentlest squeeze is sufficient to collapse a critical fluid into invisibility. This sounds absurd, and experimentally one can never observe such extreme behavior, because maintaining a substance exactly at its critical point is too difficult–the critical state is too unstable. but one can see the compressibility start to increase very rapidly as the critical point is approached. [p. 228]

A correction: the fluctuations are unstable only below the critical temperature; above, they are stable and can grow very large if one can contrive to get the fluid close enough to the critical point and keep it there. I once was able to do that. It was such fluctuations that we were studying with our Zeno space-shuttle experiment in the early 90s. We were able to keep a very small fluid sample stably poised some 3-millionths of a Kelvin (i.e., a centigrade degree) above its critical temperature to study the density fluctuations. The compressibility was so high that we had to do this in earth orbit (so called "micro-gravity") so that gravity itself would not move the fluid away from the critical point.

Still later the topic was networks and how they organize their connections and related topics, including a discussion of the Kevin Bacon degrees-of-separation game. Can all actors be connected to Kevin Bacon in just 6 or fewer steps? Is this deeply significant? Not really.

And what of the must burning issue: Is Kevin Bacon really the center of the movie universe? To answer this, one must calculate the average Bacon Number for the entire network and see how it compares with the equivalent measures for the other actors: the Elvis Number, the Bogart Number, the Brando Number, and so on. If Kevin Bacon really is the most important linchpin in the network, all other actors will, on average, be closer to him than to anyone else.

It turns out that not only is Kevin Bacon not the most important hub of the network, he is not even in the top one thousand (the list of course changes daily as new films are made). Currently up at the top is Rod Steiger (the average Steiger Number is 2.652), followed by Christopher Lee, Dennis Hopper, Donald Pleasence, and Donald Sutherland (who appeared in the movie version of Six Degrees of Separation). Marlon Brando is number 202, Frank Sinatra number 443. By the time we get to Kevin Bacon's level., the differences in the average Actor Number that separate successive actors in the list are tiny, about 0.0001.

So why was Kevin Bacon picked for this game? The answer contains the entire essence of a small world: in such a network, everyone appears to be at the center. Some are more "central" than others–but not by very much. Even relatively minor actors like Eddie Albert have a comparable network status to major stars. (Donald Pleasence was a fine actor but hardly a superstar.) [pp. 369–370]

Finally, a little quotation from Pericles [quoted on p. 425]:

Even if only a few of us are capable of devising a policy or putting it into practice, all of us are capable of judging it.

Posted on February 25, 2007 at 19.20 by jns · Permalink
In: All, Common-Place Book, It's Only Rocket Science

8 Responses

Subscribe to comments via RSS

  1. Written by S.W. Anderson
    on Tuesday, 27 February 2007 at 15.46
    Permalink

    I'll springboard off the Pericles quote and title of this to comment on one portion of what Ball discussed: free-market fanatcism and rectitude, and a crashing market.

    People invest in companies that go public based on the value of the firms plus hunches about future business success and profitability. As a company's stock increases in value, less-swift investors jump on the escalator thinking what is is what will be. That is, if the stock looks good to so many others and has been rising, it will keep doing so. These investors neither know nor care much about assets, debt levels, balance sheets, market share and so forth. They are really market players, in the big-ca_sino sense.

    What this means is that a stock market that's doing at all well tends to attract large numbers of speculators. Their participation distorts the market, creating an ever-growing speculative bubble that inevitably bursts.

    Inevitably, then, an unregulated free market always tends toward boom and bust — what folks of the Milton Friedman/Wall Street Journal turn of mind refer to antiseptically as "the business cycle."

    Whichever you call it, it's a predictable boom-and-bust proposition in which the rich get richer during booms and often during busts as well, while the poor always get poorer during the busts.

    How so? Because the rich withstand their losses in a bust and go on to pick up greatly deflated shares in solid companies that will make them much wealthier when the next boom hits.

  2. Written by rightsaidfred
    on Friday, 2 March 2007 at 16.04
    Permalink

    S.W., that was one of your better disquisitions on money matters.

    I would draw a distinction between "markets", and "free markets", the latter being a special case, practically unobtainable (a critical point?).

    Maybe I'm brainwashed, but I see all human economic matters organized into markets. We have markets for corrupt Cuban bureaucrats, and markets for Penelope Cruz movie memorabilia. Some markets are better than others.

    >As a company's stock increases in value, less-swift investors jump on the escalator thinking what is is what will be.Inevitably, then, an unregulated free market always tends toward boom and bustrich get richer during booms and often during busts as well… [because the rich] go on to pick up greatly deflated shares in solid companies

  3. Written by rightsaidfred
    on Saturday, 3 March 2007 at 06.47
    Permalink

    It appears my last post came out a bit garbled. Oh, but it was so witty and wise in its original form.

    I was a bit jarred by this: "After we'd spent quite a bit of time using scientific models to understand some of the complexity of the market and larger economic systems, suddenly traditional economic theories seems hopelessly naive and more the product of wishful thinking than critical thinking."

    The social sciences are a bit insecure when compared to the rigor and "hardness" of the natural sciences. I vaguely recall an anecdote where an eminent physicist was somewhat crudely asked what he was going to do now, since he was past thirty years of age, and most discoveries in physics are done by those under thirty years, and he replied, "I guess I will study economics".

    "Markets" seem like a natural phenomenon in human interaction, something that occurs either for good or ill, like water freezing: it can break my pipes, or give me a nice surface to skate upon. Central authorities can substitute their dictates and fiats, but they are still trying to satisfy a market.

  4. Written by S.W. Anderson
    on Tuesday, 6 March 2007 at 00.29
    Permalink

    It doesn't have to be case of central authorities arbitrarily issuing dictates and fiats, RSF. Traffic lights have the capacity to waste my time and increasingly expensive fuel. But they also offer some protection against being broadsided or being trapped for indefininte periods trying to get across an intersection.

    Unregulated markets invite every kind of scam and ripoff imaginable. Considering how many cheat in regulated markets, the prospect of completely free markets is enough to chill the blood.

    Interestingly, BTW, when it comes to stocks and other investment instruments, regulation not only serves to help protect investors and businesses, but also people who own no stocks or bonds and who don't operate a business. That's because losses due to market busts — jobs, money, business failures — tend to affect everyone involved in the economy.

    Thus, the people as a whole have a real stake in seeing to it markets are kept as fair and transparent as possible. That, of course, is accomplished through oversight and regulation.

  5. Written by jns
    on Wednesday, 7 March 2007 at 22.24
    Permalink

    Sure, Fred, markets can be everywhere — generalizing the idea to the abstract seems like it could have useful validity, at least over some broad area. And saying that markets arise "naturally" seems fair enough, at least for as long as we've had a spirit and practice of trading materials and goods and services and labor for each other.

    I would, however, move quite judiciously from the idea of "natural market" to the idea that "free markets" are "natural", that unregulated markets are somehow a desirable, pure natural state. That's as easily a picture promoted by those who benefit from "free" markets. I think our society is free to regulate corporations and markets as it sees fit.

    So, one might ask what sort of regulations is most beneficial; "beneficial" there, of course, implies "for whom", which tends to be where the discussion always gets heated and/or interesting.

    But, that aside, the point from the book is that some mathematical modeling, using these ideas from condensed-matter physics, might shed more light on how markets (even abstract ones) operate and how general properties emerge from the actions of individual agents, which might gives us clues about how to regulate markets to achieve our desired goals, once those goals are settled by other means.

    Alas, I don't think you'll find "free markets" will have much to do with a critical point; you might have been thinking of it as an asymptote, a value (or, by extension, characteristic) approachable only at infinity.

  6. Written by S.W. Anderson
    on Wednesday, 7 March 2007 at 23.33
    Permalink

    I'm probably getting in over my head, but here goes anyway.

    I'm skeptical about ideas from condensed-matter physics, or any such discipline, being of much help with understanding markets or predicting behaviors and outcomes of people participating in markets. It seems to me any such attempt would have to be based on underlying assumptions such as participants always acting rationally.

    In reality, people have a remarkable, irrepressible capacity for acting irrationally.

  7. Written by jns
    on Wednesday, 7 March 2007 at 23.42
    Permalink

    In a good scientific stance, you should be skeptical; it leads to thinking, insight, and understanding.

    This is one of the remarkable things to emerge from the book and from the models. Indeed, the looming prediction seems to be that markets are unpredictable in most useful ways. Nevertheless, the simplest assumptions made about a large number of agents acting sometimes independently, sometimes not independently, and not at all what one would call rational agents (a simplifying assumption only for traditional economic models) can lead not only to notably complex behavior (this is a lesson from "chaos theory"), but the models can exhibit what most people recognize as features of the markets.

    So, it seems unlikely that we'll understand markets totally in any sense anytime soon — and not in a way that leads to making a killing — but we may be gaining some understanding and coming to realize that all that unpredictable behavior is not so unpredictable.

    One point of the book is that although individual people may have free will and act more or less independently, they are still surprisingly predictable in the aggregate, an observation likely to infuriate most people who are determined to be unpredictable — but even they can fit into the picture!

    But then, I don't think I can explain it nearly so well here as Ball did in his book.

  8. Written by rightsaidfred
    on Thursday, 8 March 2007 at 07.51
    Permalink

    "One point of the book is that although individual people may have free will and act more or less independently, they are still surprisingly predictable in the aggregate, an observation likely to infuriate most people who are determined to be unpredictable — but even they can fit into the picture!"

    This reminds me of the story where B.F. Skinner was talking to someone about the prediction and control of human behavior. The fellow was somewhat agitated about the issue, and said, "if man thinks someone is predicting and controlling his behavior, he will go mad". To which Skinner said, "Psychotic behavior can also be predicted and controlled".

    One point I would like to add is that economists mostly talk about "perfect markets", which I believe would incorporate regulatory mechanisms to acheive societies goals. "Free" seems something more used by political types, for the positive connotations of that word.

Subscribe to comments via RSS

Leave a Reply

To thwart spam, comments by new people are held for moderation; give me a bit of time and your comment will show up.

I welcome comments -- even dissent -- but I will delete without notice irrelevant, rude, psychotic, or incomprehensible comments, particularly those that I deem homophobic, unless they are amusing. The same goes for commercial comments and trackbacks. Sorry, but it's my blog and my decisions are final.